A Historical Overview of Venture Capital in Nova Scotia

For much of the 20th century, angel investment and venture capital (VC) played a minor role in Nova Scotia’s economy. Today, however, Atlantic Canada’s start-up and VC community is booming, particularly in Halifax. To understand why these investment tools are succeeding in the region, it is instructive to review the history of VC in the province from the perspective of supply factors and demand factors.

Access to capital and credit in Nova Scotia has been constrained historically. Economist Dane Rowlands, for example, argues that “The view that the venture capital market is weak in Atlantic Canada is supported by the findings of Association of Canadian Venture Capital Companies. Of the 341 venture capital investments undertaken by the 56 active venture capital funds in Canada in 1993, only two were in Atlantic Canada.” One common view was that Nova Scotia suffered a geographical disadvantage via its removal from centers of finance in Canada and the United States. As political scientists Rodney Haddow put it, “There has long been an article of faith in Atlantic Canada, supported by some research, that banks are reluctant to lend in the region, and that the region consequently suffers from a chronic lack of credit.” Rowland’s conclusion in 1996, though, was that the main constraint on VC was lack of demand: “Demand for venture capital supplied on a commercial basis is relatively low in Atlantic Canada. Little evidence suggests that a shortage of venture capital actually exists in the region.”

This lack of demand is the result of many different factors. First and foremost, the Nova Scotia economy traditionally comprised primary sectors such as mining, forestry, fishing, and steel and banks typically dominate early stage financing in these industries (or through the use of convertible bonds). In contrast, VC investment is usually an individual investor or fund manager taking an equity stake with uncertain returns. Demand for robust angel markets, therefore, did not truly arrive until Nova Scotia’s economy began diversifying in the 1990s.

Emerging sectors such as Information and Communications Technology (ICT) coincided with a new awareness of angel investment among politicians and economic development officials. A 1991 policy-direction paper authored by then-leader of the Nova Scotia Liberal Party Vincent MacLean was particularly prescient and it gives a vivid glimpse of how focus was shifting toward ways of developing VC markets:

“Governments must and, as we will see, can help provide the capital required for start-up and for expansion, but not public money, and not free money. Rather, what is required is access to a pool of capital willing to make equity investments in the economic development of this region…The availability of capital is a major constraint on business and industrial start-up and expansion in Atlantic Canada. Therefore all avenues of providing patient, long-term capital to sound enterprises in the region need exploration.”

The paper may be the first recorded interest of a provincial party leader in developing angel markets, insofar as “patient capital” has long been synonymous with angel investment. However, MacLean’s quotation, and it’s allusion to “free money,” must be read in the context of the province’s development policies: the fiscal constraints of early 1990s featured a growing consensus against expensive industrial policies that experts saw as low-impact and high-cost. Furthermore, the public often displayed skepticism about favouritism, patronage, and corporatism.

As detailed in The Savage Years, the reform era of the 1990s included an effort to redesign Nova Scotia’s economic development policy to depoliticize and cost-minimize various programs. Among MacLean’s proposals were the creation of a Nova Scotia investment vehicle eligible for retirement accounts and “a more all-encompassing plan, where all local investment results in tax credits, and where a wider, more diversified range of companies are eligible.” This plan would encourage community investment while controlling costs and decentralizing decision making.

The latter proposal came to fruition shortly thereafter, in 1993, when the Nova Scotia provincial government enacted the Equity Tax Credit Act, the stated intent of which was “creating an important pool of venture capital for the province” by encouraging investment in small- and medium-sized businesses. The Act created a 30 per cent “equity tax credit” (ETC) for investments in businesses with fewer than $25 million in assets and revenues, a head office in the province, and at least 25 per cent of wages paid in-province. Nova Scotia’s government raised this rate to 35 per cent in 2010 and the maximum annual tax credit to $17,500, or 35 per cent of a $50,000 investment, with a five year holding period. ETCs immediately proved popular and uptake accelerated into the late 1990s.

ddddffff

Interest in developing Nova Scotia’s venture capital market continued through the mid 1990s and, in 1994, the Atlantic Provinces Economic Council (APEC) submitted a report to the Working Committee on Venture Capital titled Equity Investment in Atlantic Canada: A Key to Entrepreneurial Expansion. Among its recommendations was the creation of a privately-managed $30 million Atlantic Investment Fund (AIF) for the four Atlantic provinces. This proposal would sit relatively idle for nearly two decades until the 2013 announcement of Build Ventures, currently capitalized at $48.5 million. 1994-5 also saw pass the Innovation Corporation Act, establishing Innovacorp as a crown corporation involved in early stage VC (and absorbing the Nova Scotia Research Foundation).

The 2001 tax credit review by the provincial Department of Finance echoes the buzz around VC from the time: Nova Scotia is gaining a national profile in the venture capital community. This is largely attributable to the favorable economic performance of the Halifax area in recent years.

All this history is just to show that the resurgence of the VC community in the last few years is not without precedent. In a future post, I will turn to the contemporary landscape, and assess the viability of Nova Scotia’s start-up landscape going forward.

Samuel Hammond is an AIMS on Campus Student Fellow who is pursuing a graduate degree in economics at Carleton University. The views expressed are the opinion of the author and not necessarily that of the Atlantic Institute for Market Studies

Investment in Education: A Free Market Approach

If investment is what drives a better future, and students are the future, who then can possibly be against investments in education? The need for educating our future is certainly something that should never be understated. Unfortunately, these good intentions have been the basis of political hubris for policies that hurt the very people they intend to help.  Such is the nature of the government’s student loan program and its attempts at alleviating financial burdens for students through artificially cheap and easy credit.

In a free market economy, private lenders are free to decide to whom they will lend their money. Naturally, they tend to avoid risky ventures and look towards safer investments that have promising returns.  Because lenders naturally prefer to keep their money now rather than to receive it in the future, a promise of a sufficient interest incentivizes them to save and invest. The borrower must earn the trust of the lender and thus behave accordingly in pursuit of a venture that both sides believe will leave them better off. This also means that some individuals will be excluded from borrowing money because their ventures are too risky or not an efficient use of scarce capital.

Government student loans disregard this need for trust and forces lenders, the taxpayers, to lend to students at low rates regardless of whether or not these students can realistically repay the loan. This creates the false signal for students that perhaps it’s not as much of a bad idea to pursue that major in, say, Latin or Art History.  The more ironic aspect of this is that it creates inequality. It enriches students who would have otherwise afforded higher interest rates anyway because the nature of their highly valued degrees provides more job opportunities immediately after graduation and with good pay. On the other hand, students who have been incentivized to take low valued degrees find themselves struggling to get a job and unable to pay back the loan.  To rub salt in their wounds, their degree loses its value progressively as more and more new students get access to easy credit to enroll into that same degree on the false premise that it is valued. Or perhaps a student is well aware that that Arts degree is not valuable at all and recognizes the bubble, but what can he do? Perhaps the worthwhile degrees are too competitive for him while the other programs he can enter are no better valued. If he does not join in he misses out because an Arts degree became the new high school diploma. An oversupply develops with distorted incentives in place to keep it growing.

The full costs of the student loan program are unknown because cheap credit diverts capital away from productive enterprises as it is productivity must necessarily precede taxation. How the taxpayers who are subject to the market pressures of profits and losses would have otherwise used the $15 billion dollars put into the student loan program is unknowable. This is not to say that there would be no loans for students, but fewer loans for unpromising degrees bringing less of a strain on the productive agents which are being taxed to provide the credit.

-Ian CoKehyeng